A question raised over dinner last week. A group of N diners are dining out and the bill is $100. In scenario A, they are splitting the check N ways, with each paying by credit card and separately entering a gratuity for their share of the check. In scenario B, one of them is paying the whole check.
In which case do you think the total gratuity will be larger? Some thoughts:
- Because of selection bias, it’s not enough to cite folk wisdom that tables who split the check tip less (as a percentage): At tables where one person pays the whole check that person is probably the one with the deepest pockets. So field data would be comparing the max versus the average. The right thought experiment is to randomly assign the check.
- Scenario B can actually be divided into two subcases. In Scenario B1, you have a single diner who pays the check (and decides the tip) but collects cash from everyone else. In Scenario B2 the server divides the bill into N separate checks and hands them to each diner separately. We can dispense with B1 because the guy paying the bill internalizes only 1/Nth of the cost of the tip so he will clearly tip more than he would in Scenario A. So we are really interested in B2.
- One force favoring larger tips in B2 is the shame of being the lowest tipper at the table. In both A and B2 a tipper is worried about shame in the eyes of the server but in B2 there are two additional sources. First, beyond being a low tipper relative to the overall population, having the server know that you are the lowest tipper among your peers is even more shameful. But even more important is shame in the eyes of your friends. You are going to have to face them tomorrow and the next day.
- On the other hand, B2 introduces a free-rider effect which has an ambiguous impact on the total tip. The misers are likely to be even more miserly (and feel even less guilty about it) when they know that others are tipping generously. On the other hand, as long as it is known that there are misers at the table, the generous tippers will react to this by being even more generous to compensate. The total effect is an increase in the empirical variance of tips, with ambiguous implications for the total.
- However I think the most important effect is a scale effect. People measure how generous they are by the percentage tip they typically leave. But the cost of being a generous tipper is the absolute level of the tip not the percentage. When the bill is large its more costly to leave a generous tip in terms of percentage. So the optimal way to maintain your self-image is to tip a large percentage when the bill is small and a smaller percentage when the bill is large. This means that tips will be larger in scenario B2.
- One thing I haven’t sorted out is what to infer from common restaurant policy of adding a gratuity for large parties. On the one hand you could say that it is evidence of the scale effect in 5. The restaurant knows that a large party means a large check and hence lower tip percentage. However it could also be that the restaurant knows that large parties are more likely to be splitting the check and then the policy would reveal that the restaurant believes that B2 has lower tips. Does anybody know if restaurants continue to add a default gratuity when the large party asks to have the check split?
- The right dataset you want to test this is the following. You want to track customers who sometimes eat alone and sometimes eat with larger groups. You want to compare the tip they leave when they eat alone to the tip they leave when part of a group. The hypothesis implied by 3 and 5 is that their tips will be increasing order in these three cases: they are paying for the whole group, they are eating alone, they are splitting the check.
(Thanks to those who commented on G+)
4 comments
Comments feed for this article
February 23, 2012 at 3:57 am
Anonymous
Rounding could be more important than shame/generousity.
I imagine this would act to make tips on small transactions a higher percentage of the bill.
In scenario B1, the person handing over the cash might round the bill up to pay the tip and then request a more specific amount from the friends than they would have handed over directly to the waiter in A.
One tangent: splitting the bill might be seen as extra effort by the restaurant staff, so people might think they deserve a bigger tip.
February 23, 2012 at 6:50 am
Angry Dude
My personal experience is that B2 always over tips, by a wide margin when one person pools the bill. Not wanting to undertip, and cause the table to dig deeper, or stiff the poor sot who volunteered to sum the $, many people assume others won’t tip and precompensate.
Further, someone at the table usually calls out what they think is a reasonable tip. It seems the people who do this are inveterate over tippers, this shaming others into overtipping.
When the nil isn’t pooled, my experience is that b2 also overtips. Some feel others might stiff, or view the tipping as a competition for server’s gracefulness.
I suspect there is an age or economic related factor. I am middle aged, with young adult children, and suspect that a group of teens may do the exact opposite.
February 24, 2012 at 8:19 am
HBK
Re the last point: it could be that large groups tend to remain in the restaurant for longer, but do not order proportionately more. They are hence less lucrative customers than the same number is people on tables of two.
March 20, 2012 at 12:48 am
Danny Lynch
Your “thought experiment” in #1 is called credit card roulette. I agree that rounding is probably a big factor here.